Se pregunta el articulista: ¿Por qué las sucesivas y
recurrentes crisis de los sistemas económicos capitalistas no han conducido,
tanto en los EE.UU. como en Europa, a la adopción de las recetas propugnadas
por las teorías más dirigistas?
History’s Missed Moment
Why did the greatest failure of laissez-faire capitalism since the Great
Depression lead to a turn to the right rather than the left in both Europe and
the U.S.?
Robert Kuttner | September 28, 2011
The epic
financial crash of 2007–2008 should have produced a massive political defeat
for the conservative ideology whose resurgence began three decades ago. Its
signal achievement, liberated finance, did not reward innovation, enhance
economic efficiency, or produce broad prosperity. Rather, the result was a
speculative bubble followed by a severe crash. Along the way, the super-rich
captured a disproportionate share of the economy’s gains, while other incomes
stagnated. In the aftermath, ordinary people have suffered large losses of
earnings, assets, social protections, and hopes for their children.
By any
measure, therefore, 2008 was primed to be a political watershed on a par with
1932. History delivered a profound teachable moment for American progressives
and European social democrats. But, to borrow from T.S. Eliot, between the idea
and the reality fell the shadow. Three years after the financial dominoes
toppled, right-wing ideas are ascendant and right-wing policies reign. Instead
of reform and recovery, governing elites are delivering austerity. As the
economy keeps sinking, the democratic left is in disarray nearly everywhere. In
most Western countries, center-right parties govern and far-right movements are
on the march.
The
historian A.J.P. Taylor described the revolutionary year 1848—in which abortive
liberal democratic revolutions across Europe were all crushed—as a moment when
“history reached its turning point and failed to turn.” It would not be an
exaggeration to view 2008 as the most stunning missed moment in modern
political history.
How could
this have happened? If laissez-faire could not be reversed as a practical and
intellectual failure after a second massive financial crash on the conservative
watch, when can progressives ever expect to rebuild a broad popular
constituency for a managed form of capitalism? The explanations cannot just be
idiosyncratic or personal—Barack Obama’s conciliatory temperament, Gordon
Brown’s dour manner, or Strauss-Kahn’s predatory libido. The patterns are too
pervasive. The story has to be deeply structural.
Many
Americans look to Europe, long the home of a more social brand of capitalism,
as a counterweight to American conservatism. A month of conducting interviews
in six European countries, however, persuades me that Europe is afflicted by
deep trends common to both sides of the Atlantic, though with instructive
variations on the theme. If American liberals and European social democrats are
ever to regain political momentum, we need to understand why we don’t have it
now.
Fatally Compromised
One key
explanation is that supposedly center-left governments were complicit in the
financial deregulatory policies that led to the collapse. So when the crash
came, the moderate-left parties of Bill Clinton in the U.S., Tony Blair in
Britain, Gerhard Schröder in Germany, Wim Kok in the Netherlands, and several
others were not a credible alternative. Barack Obama turned out to be more
Clintonian than Clinton.
Blair had
continued Margaret Thatcher’s policies of making London as hospitable as
possible for the bankers whose recklessness would bring on the collapse.
Clinton and his aides were, if anything, more responsible for financial
deregulation than either president Bush. That legacy lives on in the Wall
Street–oriented team advising Obama. Schröder not only destroyed a more stable
and regulated industrial/financial system in Germany but sponsored labor-market
reforms that weakened unions, undercut wages, and widened inequality. In the
Netherlands, Kok promoted a version of labor-market flexibility that led to
relentless pressure to cut labor costs and job security and split the
constituency of his Dutch Labor Party.
Given this
legacy, social-democratic parties from the Baltic to the Balkans have neither
the political credibility nor the economic program to be a plausible
opposition-in-waiting. Protest has splintered, with far-left parties, Greens,
and especially right-wing populists all making gains at the expense of social
democrats. Also, over three decades, as left parties mellowed into
“center-left” ones, they came to think of themselves as parties of government.
When times turned hard, social democrats were the quintessential establishment
party that was failing to solve problems.
There are
two basic schools of thought on why the left moved toward the center. For some,
the Keynesian welfare state hit a wall. By the 1970s, welfare protections had
become too generous, taxes too high, bureaucracy too stultifying, labor markets
too rigid, and growth too slow. This was, of course, the right’s critique, but
many moderate leftists concluded that the neo-liberals, with their call for a
bracing dose of market competition, were not entirely wrong.
In fact,
the exaggerated story of welfare-state rigidity more nearly described Britain
or the Netherlands than flexible Sweden or Denmark. But after the hard-right
Reagan-Thatcher interlude in the 1980s, chastened labor and social-democratic
parties (except in Socialist Francois Mitterrand’s France) returned to power
with a more temperate form of neo-liberalism, both to steal the right’s thunder
and to preserve what they could of welfare capitalism.
According
to the second school, what occurred was mainly a power shift. In this view, the
stagnation of the 1970s was initially the result of the collapse of the stable,
pro-growth Bretton Woods monetary system and the OPEC oil-price increase.
Though not the fault of social democracy, stagnation and its remedies empowered
the right. “The opening up of capital markets gives multinational companies and
banks immense leverage to influence policy,” says Ola Pettersson, chief
economist of the Swedish Trade Union Confederation. “It’s the politics of
blackmail.”
With the
turn to laissez faire, a nation with progressive taxes, high wages, economic
regulation, and decent social benefits stood to scare off investors and lose
market share. Under Mitterrand in the early 1980s, France learned to its
chagrin that in a global capital market, democratic socialism in one country
couldn’t work; investors fled, stressing the franc. A sobered Mitterrand moved
to the center. Other social democrats, such as Schröder in Germany and Blair in
Britain, embraced the neo-liberal recipe more deliberately, even ardently. They
were rewarded by a political alliance with the banks. In Scandinavia,
social-democratic governments in power in the 1990s attempted a suppler blend
of market incentives and welfare protections. But everywhere, left parties
found themselves with less room to maneuver.
There are
elements of truth in both ac-counts. Undeniably, however, neo-liberalism has
fed on itself. A little leads inexorably to more. Liberate capital, and you
increase its political power. Weaken the state with privatization and
deregulation, weaken unions with more “flexible” labor markets, and you not
only reap more of a free-market economy, you end up with less civic solidarity
and a fragmented polity. You remove the political and institutional
counterweights to the power of organized business. In good times and bad,
capital rules.
Over the
past three decades, some on the center-left convinced themselves that the
hegemony of financial capital could coexist with a progressive “supply side”
formula of more investment in human capital. That strategy, necessary but not
sufficient, is now defunct. It has neither produced enough good jobs nor
rebuilt political majorities. It failed either to contain the steady erosion of
core social protections or to prevent rapacious bankers from wrecking the
economy.
Much of
this story has close echoes on our side of the Atlantic, but there are three
uniquely European elements: immigration, demographics, and the role of the
European Union.
Indigestible
Immigrants
On July 22,
tolerant Norway suffered an improbable episode of terrorism. A lone gunman
slaughtered 69 people at a Labor Party youth camp on the island of Utøya, after
setting off a car bomb in downtown Oslo that killed 8 others. At first,
Islamist extremists were suspected, but the gunman turned out to be an
anti-Islam extremist—a militant former member of Norway’s right-wing Progress
Party.
Norway, as
it happens, is the sole nation in Europe with a popular and effective left
government, led by the Labor Party. The country has a well-regulated financial
system, 2.8 percent unemployment (in July 2011), and a budget surplus, and it
has largely escaped the global economic crisis. It helps that the place is
swimming in North Sea oil.
Yet the
Progress Party is Norway’s second-strongest party, with 22.9 percent of the
vote in the 2009 election. Nativist parties take similar shares in Denmark (14
percent in 2007), the Netherlands (16 percent in 2010), Finland (19 percent,
virtually tied with the Social Democrats, in April 2011), and Austria (28
percent in 2008)—all nations that have been the heartland of European social
democracy. In France, which has a runoff system of presidential elections,
Marine Le Pen of the far-right National Front could well edge out the Socialist
candidate in the first round of next year’s election, just as her father,
Jean-Marie Le Pen, squeezed Socialist Lionel Jospin out of the first round in
2002, leaving the entire political mainstream to elect conservative Jacques
Chirac in a landslide.
One reason
immigration pushes European politics to the right is cultural isolation. Much
of Europe’s immigrant and refugee population is less interested in becoming
“Europeanized” than most migrants to the U.S. and their offspring are in
becoming American. Rather, Europe is a place to earn a living and replicate
one’s own cultural community. Native-born Europeans with their own deep
cultural traditions tend to reciprocate that sense of otherness. “With our
xenophobia, we have a hard time recruiting highly skilled people from nearby
European countries, much less scientists and engineers from India or China,”
admits Lars Goldschmidt of the Confederation of Danish Industry, “in part
because spouses are made to feel so unwelcome.”
Although
the U.S. has its own checkered immigrant history, it no longer strikes most
Americans as odd to hear someone from an unlikely background speaking
accentless American English. To a Dane, however, listening to the children of
Somali refugees speak perfect Danish still seems weird, and of course, they
often don’t speak perfect Danish, making it harder for immigrants and their
children to assimilate and succeed.
A related
problem is the impact of immigrants on Europe’s generous welfare state and
stressed labor market. Jobless and poorly skilled immigrants are major consumers
of services and frequently willing to work for lower wages. The native-born
working class bears the brunt. Immigrants settle in their neighborhoods and are
seen (rightly or wrongly) as taking the jobs of native citizens, crowding their
schools, disrespecting their culture, pushing up their taxes, and raising local
crime rates. The economic and political elite, cosseted in safe, charming
sections of Amsterdam or Paris, can afford to be more cosmopolitan. A friend
living in a fashionably diverse quarter of gentrified East Berlin describes his
neighborhood as “G-7 diversity”: just Europeans and North Americans, thank you.
Because
social-democratic parties rely on the native working-class vote and are
champions of tolerance, they suffer the most from the anti-immigrant backlash.
“We lost the working-class voters who are the losers of globalization,” says
Tommy Waidelich, the Swedish Social Democratic Party’s chief of economic
affairs.
The Assault on Welfare
Capitalism
Even
without the immigrant influx, slower growth has collided with an aging
population and dwindling birthrates, requiring unpopular adjustments in a
costly welfare state. High taxes buy less of the good life than they used to.
Social Democrats, as prime stewards of a social model of capitalism, face a
more skeptical electorate. But while some of the erosion of the welfare state
is the natural consequence of demographic trends, much of it is the unnatural
result of deliberate and cynical center-right strategies.
The
governing conservative parties that dominate Europe today have grown astute at
posing as defenders of the welfare state while subtly undermining its
foundations. To a visiting American liberal, the degree of privatization and
fragmentation in Europe’s once universal welfare state is shocking. The
political consequences are far reaching.
Consider
Sweden. The Social Democrats, who last governed from 1994 until 2006,
creatively introduced measures intended to make the welfare state more flexible
and provide citizens greater choice—some of them building on reforms from
conservatives. Any group of Swedes, for instance, can organize a local school
that competes with the official state school. Many government agencies
providing services have to compete with private rivals to win contracts. The
pension and unemployment systems have enhanced elements of choice. Many of
these reforms made sense, both to keep the bureaucracy on its toes and as an
inoculation against further privatization.
But when a
center-right coalition narrowly won power in the 2006 election, and kept it in
2010, the new government twisted the left’s reforms to weaken Sweden’s
ingeniously efficient full-employment system and undermine the trade unions
that form the core of the Social-Democratic constituency.
In the old
Swedish model, collaborative bargaining between unions and employers, combined
with substantial state outlays on retraining and job creation, allowed Sweden
to remain at full employment without overheating the economy or causing
inflation. Unions kept wage gains in line with productivity growth so that
Sweden would remain competitive. The formula famously combined an egalitarian
“solidarity wage policy”—raises for the lowest paid got first claim—with an
“active labor-market policy”—lifelong training to increase Sweden’s
productivity over time and soak up idle workers during downturns.
This highly
successful model, regularly and consensually refined, was the labor movement’s
crown jewel. Its architects were brilliant, union-affiliated economists like
Rudolf Meidner, Gosta Rehn, and Clas-Erik Odhner, household names to ordinary
Swedes. Nearly every Swedish worker was a member of a union. The unions were
key custodians of the model and the soul of the Social Democratic Party, which
was the normal party of government for most years between 1932 and 2006.
In just
five years, the conservative government has demolished much of this model,
drastically cutting outlays on active labor-market policy. It has raised the
cost of unemployment insurance and reduced benefits, causing fewer workers to
opt for coverage. The government has also made it less attractive to get
unemployment coverage through union membership, as a strategy of weakening
unions.
According
to Pettersson of the Swedish Trade Union Confederation, “The government has
found traction with the idea that lower taxes will produce increased
employment. But theirs is the low-wage, low—productivity road to job creation.
Today, when you see a TV report on the government’s labor-market policy, you
see people working on their CVs instead of getting training for good jobs.”
The
government has also changed hiring rules so that corporations can try out new
workers at lower wages for a time period of 6 months (though in some cases
employers have extended it to 24) without giving them regular employment. These
young workers, marginally attached to the labor force, are harder for unions to
reach. “The right sincerely believes this will cut unemployment,” Pettersson
says, “but these cumulative policy shifts undermine both the high-wage,
high-equality, high-productivity Swedish economic model and the Social
Democrats’ political support.”
Today, it
isn’t just local citizens who can establish what an American might call a
charter school. The players include for-profit, multinational corporations.
Many hospitals have also been privatized. As service providers cease to be
public institutions, their employees are less likely to be members of a union.
Joakim
Palme, who heads a leading policy research institute and teaches political
science at Uppsala University (and is the son of the revered, murdered Prime
Minister Olof Palme), says, “Social Democrats led the way in introducing more
competition in the public sector, but you have to be very careful about which
sectors and what rules, because it’s a slippery slope.”
Waidelich,
the Social Democrats’ economic leader, told me, “The shift has gone too far.
Originally, school choice in Sweden was for local people who had a different
idea of pedagogy. Now, under the conservatives, you have big multinational
companies based in tax havens, not even paying taxes in Sweden, running
tax-supported schools. In Sweden, 40 percent now go to alternative schools. The
schools run by corporations hire younger teachers and work them harder. The
public school takes the pupils whom the others don’t want or who don’t have
parents with the time to contribute.”
Sweden,
once a destination for worldwide social-democratic pilgrimages, increasingly
looks like the Heritage Foundation’s idea of utopia.
You might
think all these incursions would cause a citizen backlash. But the government
has softened the blow by cutting taxes. “The Conservative Party had been the
party of wealth,” says Allan Larsson, the former Social Democratic finance
minister who also headed Sweden’s labor-market system in its glory days. “In
2006, the right shifted their story. Now they say, ‘We are the party for people
who work for a living, not for those who rely mainly on benefits.’”
In the most
recent election, the center-right four-party coalition reduced the once
dominant Social Democratic Party to just 30.7 percent of the vote, its worst
performance since the election of 1920. “I am afraid,” says another former
Social Democratic cabinet minister, “that a lot of the structural damage to our
model and political damage to our party is irreversible.”
The
conservative strategy, says Joakim Palme, boils down to four elements: Reduce
and fragment the welfare state while preserving core benefits. Give tax cuts to
the middle class. Lower the reservation wage (the lowest wage that will attract
workers), but subsidize it with tax credits. Dilute active labor-market
policies. Add drastic financial deregulation, and this describes the right’s formula
throughout the continent. The view from the Netherlands, or Denmark, or
Germany, allowing for national variations, is remarkably similar. The right’s
common strategy of embracing the welfare state while undermining its
foundations seems to work nearly everywhere—and the center-left laid some of
the groundwork.
Germany,
for example, wins praise for its ingenious system of subsidized short working
time (kurzarbeit) to reduce unemployment. Employees cut their hours, but the
losses are shared between the state and the workers, who typically keep around
85 percent of their usual take-home pay. The company gets to retain its skilled
workforce rather than helplessly watch it dissipate due to layoffs in a
downturn. German unemployment actually dropped between 2007 and 2010.
This
innovation, however, is the work of a center-right government, the Christian
Democratic Union under Angela Merkel. And kurzarbeit is part of a suite of
labor policies—of which Social Democrats were prime architects—most of which
have weakened unions, undercut wages, and splintered the welfare state.
In the late
1990s and early 2000s, Germany was governed by a coalition of Social Democrats
(the SPD) and Greens led by Chancellor Schröder. Reunification had imposed huge
costs, unemployment was rising, and neo-liberal panaceas were in the air.
Schröder made the fateful decision to liberalize capital and labor markets.
Postwar
West Germany used a “corporatist” model of capitalism, otherwise known as
Deutschland, A.G. (Germany, Incorporated). Banks owned huge blocks of corporate
stock that rarely traded, so corporations enjoyed cheap, patient capital and
did not have to face shareholder pressures for high quarterly returns. Unions
participated in corporate governance through works councils and
well-choreographed collective bargaining. There was generous investment in
worker training.
But by the
late 1990s, shareholder rather than stakeholder capitalism was in fashion. So
the Schröder government changed tax policy to discourage bank dominance of the
corporate economy and make the shareholder king. Pressure for short-term high
returns increased. Schröder drastically reduced unemployment benefits and
compelled workers to take available, low-wage jobs or lose welfare benefits
entirely. Industry-wide collective bargaining declined by nearly 30 percent in
just a decade. Union membership dropped by almost half. Wages lagged behind
productivity.
In the
neighboring Netherlands, Labor Prime Minister Wim Kok brokered a grand bargain
in 1999. Employers got more discretion to hire temporary and part-time workers,
but these workers were supposed to be accorded the same protections as those
with regular contracts. Unemployment fell. “He was hailed as a miracle worker,”
says economist Paul de Beer of the University of Amsterdam, “but it had a lot
more to do with North Sea oil and favorable macroeconomic trends—higher
worldwide growth, low interest rates—than with Kok’s reforms.”
In the
meantime, “flexicurity,” a term coined by a Dutch sociologist in the 1990s to
describe the new Dutch model, became a buzzword much promoted by the
bureaucrats of Brussels. Workers would trade job security for employment
security. Their protections would be social rather than connected to a given
job. The state would invest more in worker training. Employers would get more
freedom to hire and fire. There was nothing new or centrist about this idea;
the Swedes had been doing it well since the 1960s, under social-democratic
auspices. But as events played out, Dutch flexicurity delivered more on the
flexibility than the security.
The deal
gave new powers to employment agencies and made it easier for corporations to
keep workers in a long-term “temporary” classification. Fully 48 percent of all
workers are now part time, and it has become progressively harder for part-time
workers to get full-time jobs.
The changes
in labor law have interacted with privatization. Even the Dutch post office has
been privatized. (An EU competition directive requires that private-sector
contractors may bid to provide public services.) Self-employed messengers under
contract to the successor postal companies now deliver the mail at minimum
wages—or less.
The overall
consequence of these shifts is declining security and declining earnings. Among
young Dutch workers, fully 61 percent have low-wage jobs. Meanwhile, the
center-right government, which took power in 2002 with Labor as a junior
partner since 2006, has acted to splinter other welfare-state programs. “Health
insurance used to be mandatory and fixed,” de Beer says. “Now everyone has to
insure themselves, there are many different kinds of policies, and companies
engage in cherry-picking.” This story is all too American. What’s surprising is
to find it in the Netherlands, much less as the partial handiwork of a labor
party.
The Brussels Paradox
There was a
moment when European progressives looked to the emergent EU as a bastion of
social democracy against the Anglo-Saxon forces of rampant free markets. But
that moment, which peaked under the European Commission presidency of the
French Socialist Jacques Delors (1985–1995), has passed.
The EU,
after all, has free-market roots. Its antecedents, the European Coal and Steel
Community, established in 1951, and the original Common Market, started in
1957, were all about reducing barriers to trade. As the European project
evolved from a customs union into a political confederation, many on the
moderate left imagined that trans-European social policy would serve as a
counterweight to economic liberalization within Europe and worldwide. However,
this hope proved illusory on several counts.
First,
while the creation of a European single market in 1993 increased the power of
EU commissioners in Brussels, the basic EU law gave priority to economic
liberalization. Under the Maastricht Treaty of 1992, free movement of capital,
goods, services, and persons is fundamental constitutional doctrine. These
basic doctrines, in turn, are carried out by directives issued from Brussels.
While orders by the Brussels bureaucracy have strengthened a mixed form of
capitalism in such areas as antitrust, the environment, and the rights of
women, on balance they have weakened protections in the core areas of finance
and labor.
For
example, since 1993 workers have generally been free to take jobs anywhere
within the EU. Much of this labor migration, however, is orchestrated by large
corporations. So the European Commission in 1996 issued a directive on workers
“posted” from one country to another. On paper, the rules seem balanced. The
company gets to deploy workers as it pleases; the foreign contract workers get
the same minimum rights as the locals. In practice, however, foreign workers
often end up at the bottom of the local labor market, unprotected by either
unions or regulators. In addition, a contractor need pay only the (usually low)
social-security contributions of the worker’s country of origin—giving a
further cost advantage to the contract worker over local workers. In France,
the gap is estimated at around 25 percent. The whole process, though seemingly
regulated, drags down prevailing wages and contributes to a more laissez-faire
labor market.
In three
notorious cases, the European High Court over the past decade held that a ferry
line based in Finland could fire its Finnish workers in order to hire cheaper
Estonian workers; that a German state could not impose minimum-pay standards on
the Polish subcontractor of a German contractor; and that Swedish unions could
not compel a Latvian company to bargain collectively on a contract for work in
Sweden.
These
rulings not only allow transnational business to undermine national labor
standards. They weaken European labor solidarity by amplifying divisions in the
self-interest of national labor movements.
By
contrast, consider one of the directives intended to strengthen regulation of
capital. Thanks to the tireless prodding of Poul Nyrup Rasmussen, the former
Social Democratic prime minister of Denmark, the European Commission recently
issued a directive on the governance of hedge funds and other lightly regulated
financiers. Hedge funds and private-equity companies, which have neither the
reserve nor the reporting requirements of banks, have been faulted for several
kinds of abuses. They are fond of acquiring operating companies and then
stripping their assets for quick gain. Hedge funds are also the prime
speculators betting against sovereign debt, often using “naked” credit-default
swaps, and were big bettors in the American International Group and subprime
debacles. Generally, their operations have been totally opaque.
It was a
breakthrough that this directive was issued at all. But while the directive was
being developed, lobbyists for industry overwhelmed reformers. The final
measure, published in July 2011, is full of loopholes. You can evade most of
its provisions by incorporating offshore. The hedge-fund and private-equity
business model will continue pretty much as before. If labor solidarity is
shaky, capital solidarity is relentless.
The
post-Maastricht EU weakened social democracy in a second respect. Power is
divided among national governments, the European Commission in Brussels, the
European Parliament, the European Central Bank, the European Court of Justice,
and several quasi-autonomous regulatory agencies. The winner? Laissez-faire
capitalism. Europe, once the home of nation-states strong enough to regulate
capitalism, now has something more reminiscent of the U.S. Articles of
Confederation.
In the
U.S., at the peak of the financial crisis in September 2008, you could put the
Federal Reserve chair, the Treasury secretary, and the legislative leadership
in a small room and hammer out a rescue package. It turned out to be the wrong
package, but that’s a story for another day. Together, the Fed and the Treasury
have regulatory power over the banks as well as the power to print money and
issue bonds. The 2008 program, if misguided, was at least internally consistent
in its use of fiscal, monetary, and regulatory policy.
In Europe,
however, with a weakened governmental apparatus, private finance retains that
much more power to block structural reform. For instance, though the Greek mess
had a fairly straightforward remedy of partial debt relief and longer-term
repayment, the divided EU institutions dithered for over a year as Greece sank
into deeper recession. Even if by some miracle a majority of social-democratic
national governments won power, they would be stymied by the EU’s institutional
quagmire. Where Mitterrand, trying to go it alone three decades ago, had “only”
the power of global capital to block his program, a modern successor would also
have to reckon with Brussels, at once a bureaucratic force for neo-liberal
contagion and a dysfunctional obstacle to structural reform.
Further,
expansion of the EU has created something close to a permanent center-right majority.
Of the 27 current member states, most of the nine former Soviet satellites now
in the EU have conservative governments. Their ideal successor to Marx is not
Mitterrand but Milton Friedman. The new member states generally see their
comparative advantage in offering Western European multinationals cheap labor
forces, low taxes, and light regulation.
The EU,
finally, is increasingly seen by ordinary Europeans as an elite project. In a
time of economic troubles, the popular backlash against an ineffectual but
meddlesome Brussels is not unlike the backlash against Washington. A general
mood of anti—government sentiment is a poor climate in which to rebuild social
democracy.
On
reflection, it is not surprising that a far-flung confederation should result
in weaker government with diminished capacity to regulate transnational
capitalism. In 1939, the godfather of modern libertarianism, Friedrich Hayek, a
proponent of European federation, predicted that with a federation, “certain
economic powers, which are now generally wielded by the national state, could
be exercised neither by the federation nor by the individual states.” Hayek
should be thrilled with the result.
Politics Is Teaching
An
enfeebled movement produces feeble leaders, and weak leaders don’t rebuild
movements. Today, it is hard to think of a center-left president or prime
minister who is any kind of public hero.
One of the
20th century’s greatest social-democratic leaders, Olof Palme, was fond of
saying “Politik är att tjata.” The phrase can be literally rendered as
“Politics is pestering,” but with more positive connotations. “Tjata” is a word
Swedes use to describe encouraging their kids to finish homework. Palme meant it
as hectoring the citizenry to rise to its best and legislators to produce
effective and creative results. According to Palme’s former colleague Allan
Larsson, you could loosely translate Palme’s dictum as Politics is teaching.
Though the current crisis could be a teachable moment, we don’t see much
creative teaching from the democratic left.
Are there
any bright spots? One can take some hope from Denmark. There, the center—right
government, in power since 2001, has tried many of the same gambits as its Swedish
counterparts—the fragmentation of once comprehensive services, the weakening of
the active labor-market system, the use of tax cuts and privatization to split
the upper middle class from the coalition that supports the welfare state. But
more bureaucrats are now required to supervise private vendors of social
services, and the new labor-market system has deteriorated into a paper chase.
The government has internal divisions and has lost popularity. A left coalition
seems poised to win this fall’s election.
The Danish
version of flexicurity has been much more universal and politically popular
than the Dutch one. A series of reforms, by the last Social Democratic
government under Poul Nyrup Rasmussen in the 1990s, increased pressure on
unemployed workers to find jobs but with enhanced social supports. There was no
pressure to pursue low-wage work. That last Social Democratic era, when
unemployment fell and earnings rose, is remembered as a time of broad
prosperity.
The current
Social Democratic leader, Helle Thorning-Schmidt, told me that she thought a
lot of the damage done to the model could be reversed but added that “the
fiscal room to maneuver is very narrow.” Her party promises a new social
bargain that would raise taxes on wealthy Danes and banks, increase public
investment, lengthen the normal workweek (reportedly by one hour), repair the
damage to the labor-market system, and redouble investment in education and
training. These small steps in the right direction are constrained by Europe’s
wider recession but in context are considered bold.
Elsewhere,
the right is wearing out its welcome. In Italy, Silvio Berlusconi’s brand of
near fascism has run its course. David Cameron’s right-wing British coalition
government has lurched from crisis to crisis. Merkel is effective but not
popular.
A failed
right, however, doesn’t mean a successful left. Even with several center-left
governments, if European social democracy continues on its present path, these
gains would neither solve the economic crisis nor restore the left’s broad
credibility. Impromptu events loosely connected to economic distress, like the
August riots that broke out in Britain, or the capture of Greek anxiety by
far-left anarchist street protests, demonstrate what occurs when left parties
cease to be effective carriers of pocketbook frustrations and their remedies.
Protest turns apolitical or ugly, or worse.
In my
interviews with progressive European leaders and scholars, I encountered few
optimists but two different kinds of pessimists. The first kind contends that
because of demographic, fiscal, and economic trends, the social-democratic
welfare state that thrived during the unique circumstances of the third quarter
of the 20th century is doomed. That brand of pessimism is excessive. The
Scandinavians have demonstrated that the welfare state can be continuously
refined and combined with an efficiently productive economy. In Sweden,
conservatives have outmaneuvered social democrats for now, but the Scandinavian
economic model broadly survives. To make it work, though, you have to contain
private finance.
The second
kind of pessimist concludes that a different road exists but doubts that
today’s democratic left has the political nerve to follow it. That sort of
pessimism can be fatal.
One key
difference between Europe and the U.S.: Because of Europe’s multiparty
parliamentary systems, center-right coalitions govern while the far-right
stands outside. In the U.S., with its presidential two-party system, the
far-right has now taken over one of the two major parties. This reality,
combined with a constitutional system that facilitates blockage, prevents
government from addressing a dire economic emergency and reinforces citizen
disaffection with government in general, further energizing the far right.
Another
important difference between the American and European versions of the hegemony
of the right is that the Europeans have several legitimate alibis for the
left’s weakness—the perversity of the EU, the fiscal pressures of an older
population, and the greater political and cultural distance between Europe and
its immigrants. There is simply no European equivalent of California, much less
of Los Angeles—places where recent immigrant populations are key elements of an
effective local progressive coalition.
Both the
U.S. and Europe now have constitutional systems biased against government
activism. Of these, the European version is the more intractable. There were
good reasons for progressives to cheer on the EU project, not the least of
which were anchoring a democratic Germany within a larger democratic body and
overcoming the economic disadvantage of separate small economies and
currencies. Europe’s social democrats, however, were outplayed in the
neo-liberal architecture of the EU and its multiple institutions.
By
contrast, the impact of the multiple veto points deliberately built into the
American constitutional system can be overstated. None of it stopped Lyndon
Johnson or Franklin Roosevelt. Politics is always a blend of the structural and
the fortuitous. The difference between 1933 and 2008 was partly in the economic
circumstances that gave FDR a more dire crisis to combat. But it was also our
good luck to get a leader with the jaunty fortitude of Roosevelt in the last
great crisis of capitalism, and our bad luck to draw Obama today.
In America,
radical reform is losing out because a Democratic president, captured by
financial elites, failed to seize the moment. In Europe, reform is blocked
because most social democrats, decades ago, ceased to mount a strong challenge
to ideological and bureaucratic currents that were ultimately toxic to their
movement. Here is where Europe and America converge: Though much can be blamed
on our constitutional structures, today our politics is more dysfunctional than
our institutions. On both sides of the Atlantic, the cure is a more robust
democratic left.
To repair
managed capitalism and to redeem its own credibility, the progressive left
needs to abandon its 30-year dalliance with neo-liberalism and to embrace far
stronger remedies for the current economic crisis. They include a re-regulation
of capital to abolish the purely speculative part of the financial economy and
an abandonment of the premise that the current deflation is cured by
belt-tightening. These things go together, of course, because it is the rentier
class that is demanding austerity.
The left
does not have the power to implement these reforms anytime soon, but it does
have the power to teach. In the near term, left parties will be mostly in
opposition. They should behave like an opposition—and they may regain the
credibility to eventually return to power.
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario